Skip to main content

tv   Washington Journal Charles Blahous  CSPAN  February 12, 2024 11:03am-11:39am EST

11:03 am
what was debated and decided to washington. scroll through and spend a few minutes on c-span's points of interest. >> unfiltered view of government funded by these television companies and more including media,. >> regular here or here or in the middle of anywhere like you should have access to fast and reliable internet. a front row to democracy. the status of social security and care and annual report from
11:04 am
social security and medical board of trustees. first, a reminder of those folks are information is. >> for of them are trustees by virtue of their government offices. normally there are two members of the public, i did at one time my calling across the aisle, they attended the public base of the trustee and when there was report for the annual reports are important, they tell lawmakers on the public via
11:05 am
changes that have to be made to social security if you want to continue and by way of background, security is a unique animalmo will pretty much every federal program from acute are no what the benefits are going to be and the terms are renegotiated, you have separate allocations of taxes taken out and that's important because it derives from that structure.
11:06 am
he didn't want a program to what the benefit roles would be and we earn these benefits and therefore they can and social security has the look at that. it only works as long as lawmakers are willing to go with sthe text schedule and if they are willing to do that, we can't have this self financing system. >> here's what this year's report ss, until 2033, aer 2033 taken continued to play 77%
11:07 am
of benefits to almost the end of the century, how concerned should the public be about this? >> very concerned and one thing i'm compelled to say is that even though it may sound reassuring, we have to be cautious and not rely too much on that date because by the time the date rolls around, it's too late to solve the problem and it lies in changes you have to make and we have enough revenues the payroll taxes will pay about 77%
11:08 am
and people are getting them for decades, hold we have to do today for the long s run? reducing benefits across the board by 25%, that's a huge change. obviously lawmakers are not going to go do anything we do will be more gradual which meanw paske bigger than 25%. if you faf delay, and say what are the size of the changes that we have to make if we wait until the 2030's, by then the shortfall is so large, it's actually larger than the amount of savings you
11:09 am
can generate by cutting up all benefit claims. we would never cut off all benefit claims, but it shows by then it's too late to fix the problem. it's already late in the game. we need to take action soon. we certainly cannot afford to wait another presidential term to get the job done. host: 71 million americans per month receive social security benefits. the average monthly benefit, retired worker, about $1900 a month. disabled workers, $1500 in monthly benefits. we have a special line in this segment for those 71 million americans if they want to chat with you about this program, future of social security. (202) 748-8003 is that number. otherwise, lines for emma kratz republicans, independents as usual. what is the easiest solution here to not have that nearly 25% cut? is it raising the age of social
11:10 am
security? is it new taxes or increased taxes? is there a magic bullet here? guest: i would say the bad news as well as the good news is you have to do a little bit of everything. that means you have to have bipartisan cooperation. you will have to have republicans and democrats both participating. neither side will get their way. if you are as far left as you can be and what it all to be tax increases, those increases are incredibly large. if you acted today, you have to raise the payroll tax from 4.6% to the equivalent of 16%. even our furthest left-leaning lawmakers do not want to change the payroll tax that much. similarly on the right, if you want to do it by cost restraints, we are past the point where you can fix social
11:11 am
security without additional revenues and still maintain the current level of benefits. you will have to do a little bit of everything. eligibility age also have to be a part of the picture. there are three main factors in the equation. one is the tax burden you carry as a worker. what is the annual income you can have in retirement. the third is the number of years over which your retirement income is stretched. his, as is happening under current law, as we get older, all of that extra life is added to the amount of time that we spend as beneficiaries, none of it at it to the time that we spend as workers. what happens over time is the relationship between worker tax burden and your annual income security gets worse and worse. host: right now, people are incentivize on not taking it right when you turn 62. is there a way to increase that incentive to get people to wait
11:12 am
even longer? guest: great question. i will try to give a fairly short answer but there are several things i could say. the most common age of claim believe you are not remains 62. that is not going to work. when social security was first created, the generation that fought the spanish-american war, much shorter lifetimes than ours. they were not able to collect the full 65. today the common age is 62. the earliest eligibility age is definitely an issue. there are incentives, as you note, the later you claim, the higher your annual benefit gets. but that adjustment doesn't actually take account for the fact -- basically, that attempt to keep your lifetime benefits equal no matter how long you live which doesn't account for the fact that if you stay in the workforce, as we hope they would, continue to pay payroll taxes, they are continuing to
11:13 am
pay payroll taxes without any net change expected in their lifetime benefit. that is not a good deal for them. in my subjective opinion, we would increase both the rewards for the retirement claim as well as the offset for the early retirement claim. some other ideas have been suggested, too. in some systems abroad, he delayed credit is offered as a lump sum option. people seem to be more sensitive to the lure of getting a check for $20,000 rather than a slight adjustment to their monthly benefit. host: a viewer brought it up in our open form segment. i promise i would bring it up. he said when there are cost-of-living increases for social security, why does it go to everyone across-the-board? why not just the people who are receiving the least amount of social security, as these are the people that need it the most? the people getting the most
11:14 am
social security don't need an extra $100 a month. why not find cost savings that way and focus the cola to the people on the lower end? guest: there is certainly substantive merit to that thinking, which is that the actual cost of living, the cost of your consumption needs is less for you if you are a higher income person. you spend less of your income on consumption. you could create a rationale therefore for saying past a certain point, we will cap the cola amount. historically, social security has tried to embrace the virtue of simplicity, one cola for everyone, no special rules for this or that group. it wouldn't be that complex to put an annual cap on the size of the cola, so that you got the full amount if you are a lower income person but not if you are higher income. host: 30 minutes left, talking about social security, about the
11:15 am
future of social security in the waste of this trustees report that came out. charles blahous, currently a senior research strategist at the george mason university mercatus center. always plenty of calls when we have this topic. mary is from front royal, virginia on that line for social security recipients. caller: thank you for having me. i am curious about the other side of the social security. for instance, when an employer has to pay fica, they are able to write that off as an excise tax or something. then they receive social security as well, so it is almost as if they are double dipping. guest: the taxation of social security contributions is complicated.
11:16 am
i will try to make some sense out of it. the caller is right. the employer share of the contribution is tax-deductible to the employer. it is regarded as an expense of doing business. the employee share, the part taken out of drug wages, is not -- wages is not tax-deductible. in some ways that is artificial. most economists will tell you, in effect, both halves are coming out of your paycheck. certainly comes out of your wages, the amount of compensation your employer can give to you. another implication here is the taxation of benefits. right now, depending on your income in retirement, up to 85% of your social security benefit is subject to the income tax. this is a reflection of an
11:17 am
attempt to only tax a portion of your social security benefit that hasn't already been taxed you made the fica contribution. earlier i was talking about social security trying to embrace complicity. -- simplicity. if you really want to do it accurately for each person, each person would have a different percentage rather than 85%. what happened was, when they were trying to figure out how much, they did the number of calculations and included that 85% was a reasonable proxy for the average amount of benefit that had not already been taxed on the way in as contributions, and that is why they are taxed where they are. host: another social security recipient. doug is in florida. caller: i saw a program on c-span here about a year or so ago where they were debating social security.
11:18 am
i actually heard a republican say, we are not going to be able to get the rest of the world or us down to the rest of the world if we keep paying all of these benefits. why are we trying to go down to the rest of the world instead of trying to make the rest of the world come up with us? guest: i cannot speak to the nature of the comment or the thinking behind it. i will say, i think most policy experts, lawmakers, when they think of social security, they are thinking primarily of how to make sure it is financially sound. the things that have to be done to make sure social security can continue in its current form are not things that lawmakers find pleasant to do. either raise taxes or raise eligibility ages, or reduce the growth of the benefit formula. reality is we have to do all
11:19 am
three. politicians don't like doing any of those things which is why it hasn't been done. unfortunately what happens, the longer you delay action, the more severe those changes have to be. if we had made legislative adjustments 30 years ago, they could have been a lot more gentle, and they would not have been felt very acutely by any cohort of beneficiaries or taxpayers. unfortunately, lawmakers have not done that, delayed a long time. the more they continue to delay, the more difficult it becomes. host: why did we decide to set a cap on how much we would tax social security? guest: historically, that is because the program is supposed to provide a floor of income production. the way the program works, getting back to what i said earlier about the idea of this being an earned benefit, self financing benefit. each individual's benefit is a
11:20 am
direct function of their earnings that are subject to the social security tax. you have this individual tie between what you contribute and the benefit to which you are entitled. that's a big reason why we don't think of it as welfare. i contributed to this benefit, this is the amount i contributed. the thought was beyond a certain amount, higher income people don't need more benefits. they don't need to make contributions pass that amount. there have been many proposals. my guess is that any bipartisan solution to social security's financing shortfall would probably involve an increase in the amount of income subject to the tax. host: with that increase the amount of income subject to the tax, then equate to more osha security benefits for the person whose wages are being taxed, or are they using that money to fund other parts of the program, and there social security monthly statements stay the same? guest: exactly the right
11:21 am
question. not everyone asks the question, so i'm glad that you asked it. we have this earned benefit structure where your benefits are a function of your contributions. when you tax higher income people more, one of two things happen. either you pay more benefits to people that don't need it, all you have to sever that connection between contributions dthat is kind of crossing a rubicon in social security. once we sever that connection, we do change something fundamental about social security, where some people, as with other programs, some are paying taxes into the program and not getting anything from it, others are getting benefits that they didn't actually fund. that dynamic in other programs has led to political collisions where you have the interest of taxpayers pitted against the interests of beneficiaries, which is why we are constantly
11:22 am
saying, what are the eligibility means? if you sever that connection in social security, you risk creating that type of dynamic. there is a way to get the best of both worlds. you can, at the same time as raising the caps on wages, you can go to the benefit formula and cut the accrual rate on the higher end. the benefit formula in social security is a progressive formula where the amount of your contributions accrues a benefit. it is like a set of tax brackets but in reverse. the numbers get smaller and smaller as you go up the income chain. when you have higher income, you accrue benefits at a much lower rate. if you raise the cap wages, you can cut that on the higher end, so you don't have to sever the contribution benefit completely, but you also don't wind up losing all the savings to the system from taxing higher income
11:23 am
people by paying benefits that you don't need. host: simplicity argument? guest: if we were to do something terribly novel within the system, you can get away from the sympathy argument, but the benefit form is already there. this would just be a matter of changing the numbers to make it more progressive. host: houston, texas. line for democrats. joseph, good morning. caller: good morning. i will make this quick. my question is, how does the immigration issue help to increase the trust fund? second, is the advantage plan using the demand on the system -- easing the demand on the system? host: i think he was talking medicare advantage. we are focusing on social security.
11:24 am
guest: now, substantively, higher immigration tends to increase social security. immigrants pay taxes before they become beneficiaries, and they tend to be younger than the general population. you get a considerable burst of revenue when you have higher immigration. in the trustees report each year there is a sensitivity analysis which shows how program finances look with higher levels of immigration, lower levels. program do better with higher levels of immigration. i have to caution, nothing changes the progressions too much, when you are talking inflation, immigration, fertility, the basic contours remain the same. we are just improving around the edges but immigration does improve the finances of social security in general. host: patty on the line for
11:25 am
republicans, out of the steel city. good morning. caller: i have a question and comment. i am a boomer. we put a ton of money into social security. the politicians couldn't keep their sticky hands off of it. they kept on stealing our money. now they are telling us we have a problem, we don't know if we can pay you the benefits. guest: this is a concern that many people have expressed. i think there is a legitimacy at the core of the concern, which is that, for many years, social security ran surpluses. most analysts say the effect of that was to fuel additional government consumption. they were not saved in an economically meaningful way. but that is different from saying the money was stolen or taken out of social security.
11:26 am
what has happened, every time the federal government receives that surplus money, they issued a treasury security to the trust fund. the trust fund built up a storehouse of roughly $3 trillion in treasury securities. that money is being paid back with interest. the program began to run cash shortfalls in 2010. social security's shortfalls are not because politicians stole anything, but the trust fund continues to receive all of that money represented by taxes. host: social security was set up under fdr. was there a plan for surpluses coming in? guest: another great question. until the 1980's, social security was generally run on a pay-as-you-go basis. there was an informal rule. the secretary of the treasury for fdr. there was great resistance back
11:27 am
then to the idea of social security running surpluses. there was resistance on the left and right. the right didn't want the government controlling this massive investment pool, steering it and controlling the economy. the left didn't like it either. the left didn't like the government sitting on a big stack of cash and people could be getting benefits. the two sides reached a compromise to basically have a system operate on a pay-as-you-go basis. fdr actually wanted a pre-funded system. it was run on a pay-as-you-go basis for many decades though there was no massive surplus, until one began to accrue in the 1990's and 2000s. historically, there was not really a plan for what to do when the government ran a massive trust fund because there was not intention to be one.
11:28 am
host: two the peach state. social security recipients. good morning. caller: good morning. i don't have as much of a question as i do a comment. when i was 14 or 15 years old, believe it or not, watching c-span, too. i must have been a dork. [laughter] host: not at all. caller: at this time, that discussion was still going on. we are going to run out of social security in 10, 20 years. it was in the near future. at that time i didn't know what social security was. here we are having the same discussion that we will run out of it. maybe i am being a little ignorant, but i tend not to listen to that too much anymore because it seems like it's been going on a long time. guest: first of all, i think the cool kids what c-span, not the dorks and the nerds. host: very much with you.
11:29 am
guest: the caller is voicing something that i think is important, and i think it is something that you find an undercurrent of even with lawmakers and policymakers, the idea that we have been through this before, social security survived before. there have been times when social security faced an insolvency projection and found a way to fix it. unfortunately, i think this has led to a little bit of complacency, precisely related to what you asked moments ago. historically we didn't have this surplus. in the 1970's, when things started to turns out, there was not a trust fund to draw down, so the depletion was right around the corner.
11:30 am
lawmakers had to deal with it before the annual shortfalls got too large. that morning bell went off, they acted, it was done, even if the program was just a few months away from not sending out benefit checks. i think that president has let a lot of people, including lawmakers and policy experts, to say we can do the same thing in the 2030's when the program is on the verge of completion -- depletion. unfortunately, the situation is not in any way similar to 1980's. we started running deficits in 2010, now we are drawing down the trust fund. so the gap between annual collections and benefit obligations is growing and growing and growing. technically, the trust fund doesn't run out until the 20 30's, but by then, the two lines are so far apart, lawmakers cannot close it. host: so the public trustees report says we can pay one hunter percent of benefits until 2033. you are a public trustee in 2010.
11:31 am
what were the projection you are making in 2010, 2033? guest: very similar. they bounced around, a year this way, that way, always focused on the mid-2030's. it is remarkable in this world of imprecise government forecasting, where forecast go all over the place, the trustees projections have remained markedly stable and accurate. part of that, in social security, things are marketable. when you look at medicare, health care inflation, that is more difficult to addict -- predict. social security, most of the factors are known. you know with the payroll tax is, the number of boomers, pretty much all the information you need to make a reasonably accurate projection, so the protection don't tend to move around that much. unfortunately, another thing that doesn't move around that much is the message of the trustees. when i was a trustee, saying the exact same thing. big shortfall, it's coming.
11:32 am
deal with it now, don't wait until the 2030's. people didn't listen to us but the refrain has been the same. host: about 10 minutes left with charles blahous from the george mason university mercatus center, taking your phone calls. what is your work focused on at the mercatus center, what is the mercatus center? guest: it's a research institution affiliated with york mason university. we generally do research in various aspects of public policy. my research, in keeping with my work as a trustee, on the overall arches of the federal programs. a lot of work on social security, medicare, medicaid, the federal budget as a whole. host: adam is a social security recipient. good morning. caller: good morning. social security is an
11:33 am
interesting topic. when i was teaching high school business math, i taught them about the first recipient of the social security check. they had to write an essay about social security and how it was not going to be there for them. supposedly they were supposed to get it. a couple questions. if we look at the tax on social security, started at 1984, 35% on that, adjusted now would be $99,000. another question on wep, which very few people know about. those of us that went into public life, i was in public education, have a $2000 a month retirement check for that, but i lose $285 off of my social security because i only have 23 years of substantial earnings instead of 30.
11:34 am
why couldn't that be brought down to 20 so we are not penalized for going into education? one of the things that president biden said during his presidency was that he would end the windfall earnings for those of us on social security. when we started social security, those people that lived to be 18 years old had a life exit see -- life expectancy of 68 years old. now people are living too long. host: you bring up a lot of topics. the first topic you brought up, there is that famous picture, receiving the first social security check. guest: i should have been taking notes. the second question was about the windfall elevation provision. host: there were several questions. guest: this is an interesting one, and i know it's frustrating for people who move in and out of state, local retirement plans
11:35 am
versus social security. the reason it exists is because of a quirk, shortcoming and how social security operates. the way that benefits are structured are in some ways a reflection of the fact that the benefit formula was drawn up a long time ago. your benefits are based on your lifetime average earnings. there is a progressive benefit formula that attempts to give you a better rate of return if you are on the lower income end. the consequence of that is that the system cannot differentiate between a person who earns a lot of money in a few years of earnings versus a person who earned a little bit of money in a lot of years our earnings. just working with the average. what happens is the system unintentionally steers windfall returns to people who only have
11:36 am
part of their career covered by social security, thinks they are low income people, because they cannot see the income they earned in their other employment. this is why the windfall elimination provision exists. i know it is frustrating to people who move from one form of employment to another, but you do have to have something like that, because otherwise the system would pay windfall returns to a lot of people who are not supposed to be receiving it. that said, i think there's a better way to do it then having the wep. if you had a different benefit formula, one where you accrued a benefit for each year of annual earnings, you wouldn't need a wep. we need something like that in the current system, so we cannot just repeal it and not have problems, but if we had a better type of benefit formula, we wouldn't need it. host: do presidents receive social security? did fdr ever receive it? guest:no, federal employees wert
11:37 am
in social security until the reforms of 1983. they were in the civil service retirement system. one of the reforms made in 1983 was to bring federal employees into getting that surge of payroll taxes they would be paying. they were phased out of the old civil service system, put into the new retirement system. host: anything that we should know about ida mae fuller and her story? guest: the significance of that goes back to what we were talking about earlier. the original vision for social security would be that a big fund would build out before you start paying significant benefit checks to people. ida mae fuller and others were a part of a generation that got benefits that they personally didn't pay for. she didn't spend her career paying social security taxes. her benefits were paid by taxing
11:38 am
the next generation. this is at the root of our financing shortfall today. this is an income transfer program, not savings, so it's a zero-sum game in a sense. for every person that comes out ahead, somebody else has to be behind. ida mae fuller came out from the generation that was far ahead, so subsequent iterations have to put in more to keep the system in balance. host: this is paul in delaware. democrat. good morning. caller: my question is i was wondering why there was such a reluctance to make the social security payroll tax more equitable. somebody making 150 thousand dollars pays 6% of their income. if you are making 300,000, you are effectively paying 3% of your income and the percentage decreases the more you make. why not just lifted that cap so that everyone pays 6% of their

31 Views

info Stream Only

Uploaded by TV Archive on